武夷山分享 http://blog.sciencenet.cn/u/Wuyishan 中国科学技术发展战略研究院研究员;南京大学信息管理系博导

博文

科学计量学工作者是否也要注意随机矩阵? 精选

已有 6723 次阅读 2012-8-6 06:21 |个人分类:科学计量学研究|系统分类:观点评述| 随机矩阵

科学计量学工作者是否也要注意随机矩阵?

武夷山

 

2010410号出版的《新科学家》杂志的封面文章是Mark Buchanan写的关于The Random Matrix(随机矩阵)的Enter the matrix: the deep law that shapes our reality。Mark Buchanan是美国物理学家和科学作家,2009年曾因其围绕复杂性研究领域撰写的科学作品而在意大利都灵获得拉格朗日奖。这篇封面文章说:

假定你拥有多年的经济指标数据(通胀率、就业率、股价,等等),并着手寻找其间的因果关系。J. P. Bouchaud及同事证明:即使这些变量是随机波动的,但由于观察到的最大相关性仍旧足够大,因而这些相关性显得是显著的。

这种现象叫Curse of dimensionality (维度的诅咒),意思是:大量信息的存在,使得研究一切事物都变得容易起来,但同时,“识别出的模式其实无意义”也变得司空见惯了。此时,随机矩阵方法就派上了用场,它有助于将有意义的模式和无意义的模式区分开。

 

博主:在科学计量学领域,可资利用的指标数据也越来越多。因此,计量经济学家的提醒对于我们科学计量学界也有启发意义。

李泳老师找到了Mark Buchanan那篇文章的电子版(http://treasure.1x1y.com.cn/useracticles/20100408/20100408022432574.html),而下面这篇评论文章(http://andrewgelman.com/2010/04/random_matrices/)对理解“随机矩阵”应有帮助,同时该文也发表了与Mark Buchanan不同的意见。故将此文附在下面,供参考。

 

Random matrices in the news

Posted by Andrew on 13 April 2010, 11:35 am

Mark Buchanan wrote a cover article for the New Scientist on random matrices, a heretofore obscure area of probability theory that his headline writer characterizes as “the deep law that shapes our reality.”

It’s interesting stuff, and he gets into some statistical applications at the end, so I’ll give you my take on it.

But first, some background.

About two hundred years ago, the mathematician/physicist Laplace discovered what is now called the central limit theorem, which is that, under certain conditions, the average of a large number of small random variables has an approximate normal (bell-shaped) distribution. A bit over 100 years ago, social scientists such as Galton applied this theorem to all sorts of biological and social phenomena. The central limit theorem, in its generality, is also important in the information that it indirectly conveys when it fails.

For example, the distribution of the heights of adult men or women is nicely bell-shaped, but the distribution of the heights of all adults has a different, more spread-out distribution. This is because your height is the sum of many small factors and one large factor–your sex. The conditions of the theorem are that no single factor (or small number of factors) should be important on its own. For another example, it has long been observed that incomes do not follow a bell-shaped curve, even on the logarithmic scale. Nor do sizes of cities and many other social phenomena. These “power-law curves,” which don’t fit the central limit theorem, have motivated social scientists such as Herbert Simon to come up with processes more complicated than simple averaging (for example, models in which the rich get richer).

The central limit theorem is an example of an attractor–a mathematical model that appears as a limit as sample size gets large. The key feature of an attractor is that it destroys information. Think of it as being like a funnel: all sorts of things can come in, but a single thing–the bell-shaped curve–comes out. (Or, for other models, such as that used to describe the distribution of incomes, the attractor might be a power-law distribution.) The beauty of an attractor is that, if you believe the model, it can be used to explain an observed pattern without needing to know the details of its components. Thus, for example, we can see that the heights of men or of women have bell-shaped distributions, without knowing the details of the many small genetic and environmental influences on height.

Now to random matrices.

A random matrix is an array of numbers, where each number is drawn from some specified probability distribution. You can compute the eigenvalues of a square matrix–that’s a set of numbers summarizing the structure of the matrix–and they will have a probability distribution that is induced by the probability distribution of the individual elements of the matrix. Over the past few decades, mathematicians such as Alan Edelman have performed computer simulations and proved theorems deriving the distribution of the eigenvalues of a random matrix, as the dimension of the matrix becomes large.

It appears that the eigenvalue distribution is an attractor. That is, for a broad range of different input models (distributions of the random matrices), you get the same output–the same eigenvalue distribution–as the sample size becomes large. This is interesting, and it’s hard to prove. (At least, it seemed hard to prove the last time I looked at it, about 20 years ago, and I’m sure that it’s even harder to make advances in the field today!)

Now, to return to the news article. If the eigenvalue distribution is an attractor, this means that a lot of physical and social phenomena which can be modeled by eigenvalues (including, apparently, quantum energy levels and some properties of statistical tests) might have a common structure. Just as, at a similar level, we see the normal distribution and related functions in all sorts of unusual places.

Consider this quote from Buchanan’s article:

Recently, for example, physicist Ferdinand Kuemmeth and colleagues at Harvard University used it to predict the energy levels of electrons in the gold nanoparticles they had constructed. Traditional theories suggest that such energy levels should be influenced by a bewildering range of factors, including the precise shape and size of the nanoparticle and the relative position of the atoms, which is considered to be more or less random. Nevertheless, Kuemmeth’s team found that random matrix theory described the measured levels very accurately.

That’s what an attractor is all about: different inputs, same output.

Thus, I don’t quite understand this quote:

Random matrix theory has got mathematicians like Percy Deift of New York University imagining that there might be more general patterns there too. “This kind of thinking isn’t common in mathematics,” he notes. ‘Mathematicians tend to think that each of their problems has its own special, distinguishing features. But in recent years we have begun to see that problems from diverse areas, often with no discernible connections, all behave in a very similar way.

This doesn’t seem like such a surprise to me–it seems very much in the tradition of mathematical modeling. But maybe there’s something I’m missing here.

Finally, Buchanan turns to social science:

An economist may sift through hundreds of data sets looking for something to explain changes in inflation – perhaps oil futures, interest rates or industrial inventories. Businesses such as Amazon.com rely on similar techniques to spot patterns in buyer behaviour and help direct their advertising.

While random matrix theory suggests that this is a promising approach, it also points to hidden dangers. As more and more complex data is collected, the number of variables being studied grows, and the number of apparent correlations between them grows even faster. With enough variables to test, it becomes almost certain that you will detect correlations that look significant, even if they aren’t. . . . even if these variables are all fluctuating randomly, the largest observed correlation will be large enough to seem significant.

This is well known. The new idea is that mathematical theory might enable the distribution of these correlations to be understood for a general range of cases. That’s interesting but doesn’t alter the basic statistical ideas.

Beyond this, I think there’s a flaw in the idea that statistics (or econometrics) proceeds by blindly looking at the correlations among all variables. In my experience, it makes more sense to fit a hierarchical model, using structure in the economic indexes rather than just throwing them all in as predictors. We are in fact studying the properties of hierarchical models when the number of cases and variables becomes large, and it’s a hard problem. Maybe the ideas from random matrix theory will be relevant here too.

Buchanan writes:

In recent years, some economists have begun to express doubts over predictions made from huge volumes of data, but they are in the minority. Most embrace the idea that more measurements mean better predictive abilities. That might be an illusion, and random matrix theory could be the tool to separate what is real and what is not.

I’m with most economists here: I think that, on average, more measurements do mean better predictive abilities! Maybe not if you are only allowed to look at correlations and least-squares regressions, but if you can model with more structure than, yes, more information should be better.

 



https://blog.sciencenet.cn/blog-1557-599441.html

上一篇:我抄一首赵朴初的《八声甘州》
下一篇:[转载]“淌客”的博物馆之旅
收藏 IP: 124.126.225.*| 热度|

18 许培扬 李泳 陈湘明 李本先 赫英 唐常杰 赵星 吕鹏辉 邸利会 刘广明 许海云 彭真明 鲍海飞 蒋新正 王春艳 陈筝 钟炳 胡泽文

该博文允许注册用户评论 请点击登录 评论 (12 个评论)

数据加载中...
扫一扫,分享此博文

Archiver|手机版|科学网 ( 京ICP备07017567号-12 )

GMT+8, 2024-12-24 03:41

Powered by ScienceNet.cn

Copyright © 2007- 中国科学报社

返回顶部